• Thanks for stopping by. Logging in to a registered account will remove all generic ads. Please reach out with any questions or concerns.

US hedge fund seized an Argentine naval ship

winnipegoo7

Member
Inactive
Reaction score
0
Points
160
http://www.bbc.com/news/world-africa-19827562

ARA Libertad, a commissioned training ship (has sails), was seized by Ghana at the request of NML Capital.
 
Ghana: Crew of Argentine Libertad ship board plane to fly home
By Francis Kokutse, The Associated Press
24 Oct 2012

http://www.calgaryherald.com/business/Ghana+Crew+Argentine+Libertad+ship+board+plane+home/7439616/story.html

ACCRA, Ghana - More than 280 crew of the Argentine naval sailing ship, Libertad, have boarded an Air France plane to take them home.

The sailors have been in Accra since Oct. 2 after a Ghana court ruled to keep the Libertad at Tema Port following an order served by a United States investment group NML.

Argentina chartered the plane to fly the crew home after failing to persuade the government to release the three-masted tall ship.

The Libertad is worth about $20 million, according to investors who persuaded the courts in Ghana seize the vessel for nonpayment of bonds that Argentina defaulted on during its devastating financial crisis more than a decade ago.

The ship's captain and a skeleton crew will stay behind to maintain the ship at port in Ghana.
 
You know, wars have started over things like this.  :facepalm:
 
http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-africa-20074775

An earlier plan for the sailors to fly back on an Argentine plane was scrapped because of fears that the aircraft might itself be impounded as part of the debt dispute.

 
cupper said:
You know, wars have started over things like this.  :facepalm:

Perhaps if the British had seized it.
 
MAJONES said:
Perhaps if the British had seized it.

Should the UK stump up the money to buy the ship, I would love to hear Her Majesty's speech "I now Christen this ship HMS Margaret Thatcher"
 
uptheglens said:
Should the UK stump up the money to buy the ship, I would love to hear Her Majesty's speech "I now Christen this ship HMS Margaret Thatcher"

:rofl:

.....I'd kick in ten bucks towards that.
 
Should we really be kicking Argentina when they are down?  >:D
 
uptheglens said:
Should the UK stump up the money to buy the ship, I would love to hear Her Majesty's speech "I now Christen this ship HMS Margaret Thatcher"
Better yet HMS Iron Maiden.
 
my72jeep said:
Better yet HMS Iron Maiden.

Totally agree, with a huge Eddy statue up in the bow as a figurehead.  That would totally rock,
And we could name the next one HMS Judas Priest.
 
This is interesting considering all of the "concerns" over possible Argentine aggression towards the Falkland Islands lately.  The RN recently put HMS Dauntless into the area for rotation to maintain a deterrent and presence. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-16810417

With Argentina having issues with debt collectors, it's unlikely they are in any position to launch any sort of an attack.

I too like the idea of the "HMS Iron Maiden"
 
So, Argentina took this dispute to the International Tribunal for the Law of the Sea (ITLOS) in Hamburg, Germany for resolution and this report, reproduced under the Fair Dealing provisions of the Copyright Act from Opinio Juris, explains why it found in Argentina's favour:

http://opiniojuris.org/2012/12/15/law-of-the-sea-tribunal-resoundingly-affirms-the-sovereign-immunity-of-warships-and-orders-ghana-to-release-argentine-tall-ship-ara-libertad/?utm_source=feedburner&utm_medium=feed&utm_campaign=Feed:+opiniojurisfeed+(Opinio+Juris)&utm_content=Google+Reader
Law of the Sea Tribunal Resoundingly Affirms the Sovereign Immunity of Warships and Orders Ghana to Release Argentine Tall Ship ARA Libertad

by Craig Allen

[Craig H. Allen is the Judson Falknor Professor of Law at the University of Washington in Seattle.]

On December 15, 2012, one phase of the dispute between the Argentine Republic and the Republic of Ghana over the “seizure” of the Argentine frigate ARA Libertad while in a Ghanaian port came to an end, when the International Tribunal for the Law of the Sea (ITLOS) in Hamburg, Germany ordered Ghana to “forthwith and unconditionally release the frigate ARA Libertad” and to “ensure that the frigate ARA Libertad, its Commander and crew are able to leave the port of Tema and the maritime areas under the jurisdiction of Ghana, and … that the frigate ARA Libertad is resupplied to that end.” (See Order of 15 December 2012).

The order came just one month after Argentina filed its application for provisional measures with the ITLOS. The tribunal’s decision—which should receive a warm welcome in the Pentagon—sends a clear message on the principle of sovereign immunity of warships and the readiness of ITLOS to enforce that immunity even when the warship is in the port or internal waters of another state—at least if the involved states are party to the 1982 LOS Convention.

The dispute between the two states has its roots in Argentina’s 2001 default on roughly $100 billion in sovereign debt, reportedly the largest sovereign default in history. NML Capital Investments, which owns some $1billion in Argentina’s sovereign debt, obtained judgment in a New York federal district court for $284 million in 2006. The U.K. Supreme Court later upheld NML’s right to execute its judgment against Argentina’s assets in the U.K. (NML Capital Ltd  v Republic of Argentina, [2010] EWCA Civ. 41, aff’d, [2011] UKSC 33), a decision extensively relied on by agents for Ghana during oral argument at the ITLOS.

This particular dispute before the ITLOS between Argentina and Ghana arose on October 2, 2012, during the ARA Libertad’s October 1-4 port visit to Tema, an industrial port east of Ghana’s capital, Accra. The Libertad, a three-mast tall ship, carried 330 navy cadets and crew at the time. A local Ghanaian court granted NML’s application for an injunction, which prevented the vessel from taking on the fuel she needed before departure until Argentina posted $20 million with the court, in partial satisfaction of NML’s judgment.

Argentina consistently argued that the Libertad was a “warship” under international law, declaring at one point that she is the flagship of the Argentine Navy. In fact, Ghana’s seizure of the vessel prompted several high level resignations in the Argentine Navy and intelligence agency (which was criticized for not foreseeing the seizure). Despite having earlier waived its sovereign immunity with respect to the debt instruments (and the U.K. Supreme Court’s decision upholding the broad effect of that waiver) Argentina argued that Ghana’s interference with the vessel violated sovereign and diplomatic immunity principles.

Ghana and Argentina are both parties to the 1982 U.N. Convention on the Law of the Sea. On October 30, 2012, Argentina instituted dispute settlement proceedings under Annex VII of that Convention. On November 14th, after waiting the required two weeks, Argentina filed its application in ITLOS for provisional measures under article 290 of the Convention, pending constitution of the Annex VII arbitral tribunal. ITLOS heard two days of oral arguments on November 29-30 and issued its order on December 15, 2012. The decision of the judges to order the vessel’s release was unanimous; however, five judges issued separate declarations or opinions.

A threshold question presented in an application to ITLOS for provisional measures is whether the court or tribunal that will eventually adjudicate the dispute on the merits would prima facie have jurisdiction over the dispute under article 288 of the LOS Convention. Jurisdiction under that article is limited to “any dispute concerning the interpretation or application of [the LOS] Convention.” Argentina argued that prima facie jurisdiction existed because the dispute concerned the interpretation or application of four LOS Convention articles: article 18(1)(b) on innocent passage in the territorial sea, article 32 on the sovereign immunity of warships and articles 87(1)(a) and 90 on high seas freedom of navigation.  The tribunal rejected three of the four grounds (see ¶ 61), but found that the dispute did, at least prima facie, concern the interpretation or application of article 32 (¶¶ 65-67). It should be noted, however, that the Annex VII arbitral tribunal is not bound by the ITLOS determination regarding jurisdiction over the dispute, as was demonstrated by the differing opinions on jurisdiction in the 1999-2000 Southern Bluefin Tuna cases.

Key to the tribunal’s decision was the fact that the two states disputed whether article 32 on the sovereign immunity of warships applied to such vessels while in the internal waters of a state. Argentina, relying on the opening language of the article 32 saving clause “nothing in this Convention” argued that the LOS Convention immunity did extend to warships in internal waters, while Ghana, citing the fact that article 32 appears in Part II of the LOS Convention, which addresses the territorial seas, argued that article 32 did not apply in internal waters. While not dispute the warship’s immunity, Ghana argued that the immunity was governed by customary law, not the LOS Convention, and that the dispute therefore did not concern interpretation or application of the Convention.

The tribunal first observed that “although article 32 is included in Part II of the Convention entitled ‘Territorial Sea and Contiguous Zone,’ and most of the provisions in this Part relate to the territorial sea, some of the provisions in this Part may be applicable to all maritime areas, as in the case of the definition of warships provided for in article 29 of the Convention.” (¶ 64). The tribunal then concluded that “a difference of opinions exists between them as to the applicability of article 32 and thus the Tribunal is of the view that a dispute appears to exist between the Parties concerning the interpretation or application of the Convention.” (¶ 65).

After answering the threshold question on prima facie jurisdiction under the LOS Convention in the affirmative, the tribunal then turned to the issue of provisional measures.  It noted that article 290(1) provides that such measures may be ordered “to preserve the respective rights of the parties to the dispute or to prevent serious harm to the environment, pending a final decision.” Ghana argued that no such measures were necessary or appropriate because Argentina held the keys to the Libertad’s release. The tribunal’s order took notice of Ghana’s assertion that Argentina had the ability to obtain immediate release of the vessel by payment of security to the Ghanaian courts (¶ 92). 

However, the tribunal was not persuaded that provisional measures were therefore inappropriate. It cited the continuing serious prejudice to Argentina posed by Ghana’s refusal to permit the warship to depart its port.  The tribunal observed that “a warship is an expression of the sovereignty of the State whose flag it flies” (¶ 94) and “in accordance with general international law, a warship enjoys immunity, including in internal waters (¶ 95). It then declared that “any act which prevents by force a warship from discharging its mission and duties is a source of conflict that may endanger friendly relations among States” (¶ 97) and “actions taken by the Ghanaian authorities that prevent the ARA Libertad, a warship belonging to the Argentine Navy, from discharging its mission and duties affect the immunity enjoyed by this warship under general international law.” (¶ 98). The tribunal then concluded that “the urgency of the situation requires the prescription by the Tribunal of provisional measures that will ensure full compliance with the applicable rules of international law, thus preserving the respective rights of the Parties.” (¶ 100).

The tribunal did not address the question raised during oral argument regarding Argentina’s waiver of sovereign immunity.  Argentina had argued that such waivers must be specific as to warships.  Arguably, to find prima facie jurisdiction the tribunal did not need to reach the waiver issue.

While the ITLOS decision may indeed be cheered in naval circles for its ringing affirmation of the sovereign immunity of warships (possibly also for military aircraft, although they are not defined in the LOS Convention, nor is their sovereign immunity addressed), it also serves as a reminder of the awkward position of the U.S. as a non-party to the LOS Convention (the Convention has been pending before the senate since 1994, but the senate has yet to give its advice and consent to accession). Accordingly, should a similar incident occur involving a U.S. Navy or Coast Guard warship, the U.S. would not be able to apply to the ITLOS for the vessel’s release. Should the U.S. become a party to the LOS Convention, it should also take note of the fact that Argentina shrewdly amended its article 298 declaration on October 26th (four days before instituting its first legal action under Annex VII of the LOS Convention) to remove its early rejection of the LOS Convention’s compulsory dispute settlement procedures with respect to “military activities by government vessels and aircraft engaged in noncommercial service.” (¶ 34).  In presenting the Convention to the senate in 1994, the Clinton administration recommended that the U.S. exempt military activities from the Convention’s compulsory dispute settlement procedures. Proposed declarations by the Senate Foreign Relations Committee in 2004 and 2007 adopted that position. This case demonstrates at least one potential drawback to such exemptions.


RCN members should be pleased, but it doesn't excuse the underlying problem: decades of political and economic mismanagement in Argentina which, in my view, persist today and are common to (almost?) all of Latin America including Brazil and Chile.
 
That's too bad.  I was going to buy some US government bonds, and then when they default acquire myself a US CV on its next port visit.
 
Despite repeated failues of these sorts of policies through history, people never seem to learn. Argentina continues on its self propelled downward spiral:

http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2013-07-05/argentina-applies-law-that-jails-hoarders-as-bread-prices-double.html

Argentina Applies Law That Jails Hoarders as Bread Surges
By Eliana Raszewski - Jul 5, 2013 1:40 PM ET

Argentina plans to apply a law that forces holders of wheat and flour suitable for bread making to sell stock on the domestic market in a bid to contain inflation.

Interior Commerce Secretary Guillermo Moreno announced the measure in the official gazette today. The 1974 law allows authorities to freeze prices and obliges companies to maintain supply. Those in breach are subject to fines and imprisonment.

“If the law on supply is applied, the one who should go to jail is Moreno himself,” former Economy Minister Martin Lousteau said in an interview with Radio Mitre today. “He’s to blame for the lack of wheat in Argentina.”

Argentine wheat production has decreased since 2006, when President Cristina Fernandez de Kirchner’s predecessor and late husband Nestor Kirchner set export quotas. Lousteau was appointed by Fernandez in December 2007 and resigned four months later amid disputes over a bill that sought to increase export duties, a move that led to a four-month farmer protest and failed to move through Congress.

The rising cost of wheat locally has pushed up the price of bread to 20 pesos per kilo ($3.70), double year-ago levels, according to Abeceb.com research company.

Andres Alcaraz, spokesman for the grains and oilseeds exporters associations CIARA-CEC, declined to comment on the amount of wheat held by exporters in a telephone interview from Buenos Aires. The Buenos Aires Grains Exchange yesterday maintained its forecast for wheat area at 3.9 million hectares.

Domestic Consumption
Argentina, the largest wheat producer in South America, has a domestic consumption of 6 million tons. The harvest in the 2012-2013 season was 9.8 million tons.

Wheat futures for September delivery fell 0.6 percent to $6.61 a bushel at 12:37 p.m. on the Chicago Board of Trade.

Moreno closed stores owned by Wal-Mart Stores Inc., Carrefour SA (CA) and Cencosud SA (CENCOSUD) for a few hours yesterday after the government found shortages of some goods. Grocers agreed last month to freeze prices of 500 goods and ensure supply as part of the government’s efforts to stem inflation.

While the national statistics agency said prices rose 10.3 percent in May from a year earlier, private economists estimated prices rose 23.4 percent in the same period.

Last week, the consumer protection agency recommended Argentines combat price increases by baking bread at home, posting recipes on its website under the title, “hot bread, flour at frozen prices.”

To contact the reporter on this story: Eliana Raszewski in Buenos Aires at eraszewski@bloomberg.net

To contact the editor responsible for this story: James Attwood at jattwood3@bloomberg.net

 
OK, a lot of people are not going to read this article (which is reproduced udner the Fair Dealing provisions of the Copyright Act from Foreign Affairs) all the way to the end, and that's a shame because it makes a very important point about international responsibility and why the United States - both the judicial and executive branches - have failed/are failing in their global leadership role:

http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/141588/felix-salmon/hedge-fund-vs-sovereign
sitetheme_logo.gif

Hedge Fund vs. Sovereign
How U.S. Courts Are Upending International Finance

By Felix Salmon

JUNE 24, 2014

There aren’t many institutions powerful enough to bring a sovereign nation to its knees. Most of those that are wield their power with great care; the rest are dangerous fundamentalists. Last week, the U.S. Supreme Court placed itself -- and the rest of the U.S. federal judicial system -- squarely in the latter camp when it refused to accept an appeal by Argentina against a lower-court decision. The consequences are certain to be dreadful for Argentina. More broadly, the ruling will make it more difficult for countries to free themselves from the burden of over-indebtedness. It will be very bad for international capital markets. Oh -- and it will also diminish national sovereignty.

The case involved Argentina and a group of so-called vulture funds, led by the deep-pocketed and highly litigious hedge fund Elliott Associates, which was demanding repayment in full on old Argentine debt. Elliott had first come to broad public attention in 2000, when it brought -- and won -- a similar case against Peru. That unprecedented victory against a sovereign government, although worth a mere $90 million, so deeply shocked the international financial community that it prompted the International Monetary Fund to undertake a messy and protracted attempt to create a brand-new sovereign bankruptcy court. The Argentina case is much, much bigger -- Argentina owes Elliott over a billion dollars. The total amount that it owes “holdout creditors,” as the vulture funds are more formally known, is some $15 billion. Given that other holdout firms will immediately demand any terms awarded to Elliott, Argentina is not lying when it says that it simply can’t afford to do what the U.S. courts are demanding of it -- which is to pay all the holdouts in full.

Nor, of course, would it ever want to. Argentina defaulted on all of its foreign bonds in 2002, at the end of a depression that saw its economy shrink by 28 percent, its currency devalue enormously, and millions of its citizens lose their jobs and go hungry. At the time, it was the largest debt default the world had ever seen. (Lehman Brothers would eventually break that record.) Argentina’s foreign debt went unpaid until 2005, when the country offered its creditors a deal: Give us your old defaulted bonds and we’ll give you new bonds in return, with a lower face value. You should do that, because we’ll actually pay the money we owe on the new bonds. (This also hinted that it would remain in default on the old bonds.)

Argentina was true to its word, and, after a second bond swap was finished in 2010, some 93 percent of the holders of the original debt had swapped it out for what are known as “exchange bonds.” The swap was coercive, to be sure: bondholders didn’t have much say in the matter, beyond the choice of whether or not to participate. But that’s the way of sovereign debt. If a sovereign defaults, there’s not much creditors can do to force it to pay up. That’s what “sovereign” means. Traditionally, then, most bondholders have simply accepted any exchange offer they’re given. And, in turn, such exchanges have become an established means by which countries restructure their debts to avoid remaining in default indefinitely.

The case in New York -- the one that made it all the way to the Supreme Court -- was brought by bondholders that didn’t participate in the exchange. They originally bought their debt at a deep discount, and they knew how to apply past-due compound interest calculations to make the face value of the defaulted debt balloon into the billions. They knew that it wouldn’t be easy to get paid in full, but if they managed it they would have scored one of the biggest home runs in hedge-fund history.

Thus did the cat-and-mouse game between Elliott and Argentina begin: Elliott would try to seize Argentine assets, and Argentina would try to keep them out of Elliott’s reach. At one point, an Argentine naval sailing vessel, the Libertad, was confiscated by local authorities in Ghana, with the intention that it be handed over to Elliott. The ship was released only after a ruling from the International Tribunal for the Law of the Sea.

But behind all the legal shenanigans was a serious debate about sovereign bankruptcy, or, rather, about the fact that there’s no such thing as sovereign bankruptcy. Countries do not default lightly: doing so nearly always results in the government falling, and in the country being unable to borrow money abroad for many years to come. Since most countries run deficits, being able to borrow money is extremely important.

If a country does default on debts, then it needs some way to cure that default, reenter the international financial system, and give itself and its companies the ability to fund themselves with debt. Because countries can’t declare bankruptcy, exchange offers are the next best thing. But for those to work, a debtor country needs to be able to pay the exchange bondholders without paying the holdouts. Otherwise, no one would ever participate in an exchange, and no country could ever restructure its debts.

This, then, is why Brazil, France, Mexico, and the United States supported Argentina in the Elliott case. None of them had much sympathy for Argentina itself, or its government. But they did have a vested interest in maintaining a sovereign’s right to pay one group of creditors without paying another. Indeed, it’s something that anyone who found himself in a similar situation might do: he might choose to pay his rent even if that means falling behind on credit card payments, for instance. But this is where U.S. courts started getting creative.

For years, Judge Thomas Griesa had levied increasingly strict rulings against Argentina, which Argentina had ignored. After many years of fruitless litigation, Griesa turned to a nuclear option. He ginned up a new violation by Argentina, which was embedded in something called the pari passu clause. The pari passu clause is a piece of hoary financial boilerplate that means absolutely nothing in a sovereign context. The clause, which said that Argentina’s bonds would “rank at least equally” with all its other indebtedness, makes sense only for debtors who can file for bankruptcy. Yet Griesa ruled that Argentina was in violation of pari passu. That ruling, in and of itself, was no big deal. Argentina was in violation of hundreds if not thousands of contractual obligations, and one more was hardly going to make much of a difference. But in this case, Griesa came up with a brand-new remedy to cure the newly discovered violation. And the remedy, much more than the violation itself, is what will end up transforming the world of sovereign debt.

Normally, when a borrower violates a contractual obligation, a judge will hand down a judgment against that borrower. In this case, however, Griesa went after the bondholders who had accepted 30 cents on the dollar for restructured Argentine debt. He told every other agent in the payments chain, up to and including the trustee for the exchange bondholders, that Argentina was not allowed to pay them until Elliott had been paid in full. If the trustee or anybody else helped Argentina pay its exchange bondholders, then Griesa would find them in contempt of court, assuming that Elliott had not been paid at that time.

That order was stayed pending appeal, but it is now in full effect. Make no mistake: the innocent are being punished. The exchange bondholders have done nothing wrong, and there is no way that they’re going to get their payment in full and on time, as Argentina would like. But the ruling goes well beyond punishing the innocent. It also turns the natural order of debt on its head. It used to be that having a bond was good but that having a judgment was much better. Now, however, it’s the other way around: judgments will get you nowhere, while bonds, if they have a pari passu clause, can make you all-powerful.

There’s also no logic to how this new system of jurisprudence should be enforced. The remedy seems to be available, more or less randomly, only to bondholders with a certain clause in their contracts. Worse, it actually discourages countries from making any payments at all, even if they’re both willing and able to do so, unless they can make all the payments they’re obliged to make.

Griesa’s ruling was the act of an exasperated judge at the end of his tether. And, in truth, he deserves a certain amount of sympathy: he has had the gruesome and thankless task, over the past decade, of overseeing dozens of lawsuits against Argentina. But once he had ruled, it became the job of the appeals courts -- first the Second Circuit, and then the Supreme Court -- to grapple with what he had done and to think hard about the implications.

But both of them ducked those questions. Griesa, they said, was within his rights to rule as he had done -- true enough. And Argentina should be required, under New York law, to pay its debts -- that’s true, too. But that leaves open the questions of sovereign immunity, the future of sovereign debt restructuring, and the future of New York as a financial center.

This is where the Supreme Court's ruling comes in. On June 16, it handed down a 16-page decision in a parallel and much less important case, also finding against Argentina. In that ruling, Justice Antonin Scalia explained that, once upon a time, the Supreme Court would defer to the executive branch whenever the time came to make decisions involving judicial power over sovereign states. And invariably the executive branch would seek to hold foreign sovereigns immune from U.S. judicial proceedings. The result, says Scalia, was “bedlam,” which was “abated” only by the passage of the Foreign Sovereign Immunities Act in 1976. For the past 38 years, such questions have no longer been up to the U.S. State Department, or even the president; they’ve been entirely under the purview of the courts. “Any sort of immunity defense made by a foreign sovereign in an American court must stand on the Act’s text,” he writes. “Or it must fall.”

What Scalia is saying is that it’s not his job to worry about the fate of international bond markets, or the sanctity of concepts such as sovereign immunity. He can look only within the four corners of a legal document, and see what he finds there. Nothing else matters. Which is basically what the Second Circuit said, even though it couldn’t entirely duck the sovereign immunity question -- it said that “further guidance from the Supreme Court” could settle that question more decisively. Yet, so far, the Supreme Court has remained silent. The result is, to use Scalia’s term, bedlam. Argentina wants to pay the exchange bondholders, but it can’t. Argentina doesn’t want to pay Elliott, but it has to. It is stuck on the horns of a dilemma, where every possible course of action is a bad one.

So what should Argentina do? It has said that it will negotiate with Elliott, but given how stubborn both sides are, it would be astonishing were the negotiations to bear fruit. Argentina has also said that it will not default on the exchange bondholders -- although there’s a case to be made that simply tendering payment to the Bank of New York, even if that payment is refused, is technically enough to avoid default. (Which of course would come as cold comfort to the unpaid bondholders.)

There has also been talk of trying to do some kind of new bond swap, where exchange bondholders could swap their paper again for new bonds issued in Argentina, away from the reach of U.S. courts. That seems extremely unlikely to happen, though, since only the trustee can reliably identify who the bondholders are, and the trustee would never cooperate with such a plan without Griesa’s permission.

There is one other possibility. It’s not a pleasant one -- not for exchange bondholders, not for Argentina, not for Griesa, and certainly not for Elliott. But it might just be the least unpleasant option.

In the world of public corporations, it has become popular to buy back stock instead of issuing a dividend: shareholders often have tax reasons for preferring buybacks to dividends, and companies are following their preferences. Bond issuers don’t have that option: they’re contractually obliged to make coupon payments. But once a bond has defaulted, it is possible to get a bit more imaginative. And if Argentina wanted to continue to funnel money toward the exchange bondholders, one way of effectively doing so would be to simply buy up those bonds on the secondary market. Argentina could simply take the money that it would otherwise have spent on coupons and spend it instead of buying newly defaulted exchange bonds.

Or it could go further, and attempt some kind of full-fledged de facto bond exchange. Argentina will certainly continue to issue local debt, including local bonds pegged to the dollar, just as it has done for many years. So maybe it could step up that local debt issuance, and start using the proceeds to buy back its defaulted exchange bonds. The country’s total indebtedness would not go up; if anything, thanks to the defaulted bonds trading at a discount, it might well go down. But the longer Argentina conducts that trade -- the more local debt it issued, and the more exchange bonds it bought back on the secondary market -- the closer it would come to much the same outcome as if it had simply swapped the exchange bonds for local bonds in a big formal exchange offer.

There would be serious costs to such a strategy. For one thing, Argentina would be cementing its status as a financial-markets untouchable: it would be going backward rather than forward. But at least it wouldn’t have to make the politically disastrous decision to pay Elliott -- and the other holdout creditors -- billions of dollars it can’t afford.

And if anybody started criticizing the country for being in default on the exchange bonds, Argentina could always say, quite honestly, that it has both the ability and the willingness to pay -- and that the only reason its bondholders aren’t getting paid is that the U.S. courts won’t let them be paid. Both the Second Circuit and the Supreme Court had every opportunity to avert this disaster, and instead they punted. They are the ones who should be held responsible for the fallout.


Now, the author, Flelix Salmon, a financial journalist, blames only the courts, the US Second Circuit Court and the USSC, for not disallowing Judge Griesa's understandable ruling. He suggests, and I agree, that the courts could have and should have looked beyond the law, proper, and should have asked how far US extraterritoriality can extend. But I also blame the Obama administration for not having argued, in front of Judge Griesa, that ruling as he did would be an unjustifiable intrusion into foreign policy which is not any judge's business.

Justice Scalia is wrong and so is the (existing) Foreign Sovereign Immunities Act (1976): it is not the court's (or, indeed, America's) business to sort out the "bedlam" that is the very nature of the global economy. If America wants to apply its sovereign laws to other nations then it had best invade them ~ and then support and govern them, and we have seen how well that works, haven't we? ~ or indemnify US companies, shielding them from risk, and the US hasn't got the financial where-with-all for that.

This is bad law and bad policy ... and it is 100% American.


Edited to add:

And see this. US extraterritoriality extends to both the individual and corporate levels. It, US law, is very, very powerful but it will, inevitably, draw business, investments, management fees, etc, away from Wall Street and towards London (not the safest choice) and Singapore. It is a bit like shooting yourself in the foot, in order to escape from the next battle, but forgetting that you wanted to resume your career as a ballet dancer when the war is over.
 
Today, the Financial Times reports that "Barring a last minute deal with holdout creditors, Argentina will on Monday enter technical default for the second time in 15 years."

The recent ruling (see above) by Judge Thomas Griesa in the United States District Court for the Southern District of New York even effects, generally, bonds denominated in Euros and issued in England.

The FT say, and I hope it is correct that, "Investors have so far shrugged off the legal too-ing and fro-ing as they believe Buenos Aires’ actions and rhetoric are largely for domestic political consumption. With the economy in recession, they mask Argentina’s underlying desire to regain access to international credit to fund development of the country’s huge shale gas reserves and also avert another financial crisis."
 
I know this is boring as hell but, trust me, international financial markets matter in a strategic sense. Countries have gone to war for things that are less important and countries have used war to deflect attention from deep economic problems. This article, which is reproduced under the Fair Dealing provisions of the Copyright Act from the World Economic Forum, explains some of the consequences of Elliott v Argentina:

http://forumblog.org/2014/07/elliott-argentina-debt/?utm_content=bufferecd6c&utm_medium=social&utm_source=twitter.com&utm_campaign=buffer
weforum-logo.6dbec97f91ecda11476c18553442ffad.png

What Elliott v Argentina means for global debt markets

By : Anna Gelpern

Jul 7th 2014

As Argentina prepare to face the Netherlands for a place in the World Cup final, off the pitch the country has been caught up in another battle over its debt – one that could have far-reaching consequences.

On 16 June 2014, the US Supreme Court let stand a series of lower-court rulings that could alter the way governments handle debt crises. The decision ends the battle between the government of Argentina, which defaulted on more than $80 billion in foreign bonds in 2001 and restructured most of them in 2005 and 2010, and Elliott Associates, an investment company that has been pursuing distressed governments in court for decades. For other debtors, creditors and providers of financial-market services, the battle is just beginning.

In a succession of rulings that began in 2011, federal courts in New York ordered the Argentina government not to pay creditors who reduced their claims by as much as two-thirds, unless it also paid full principal and past-due interest to the small minority of creditors led by NML Capital (an Elliott affiliate), who refused Argentina’s debt-restructuring offers. The courts used their interpretation of the pari passu (equal step) clause in Argentina’s debt contracts, which promised an unspecified measure of equality to its foreign creditors, to mandate full payment to holdouts. The courts also threatened contempt sanctions against anyone – clearing houses, payment systems, financial-market service providers around the world – who might help Argentina continue paying its restructured debt. The country now faces the choice of paying as much as $15 billion to all its holdout creditors, who hold almost identical contracts, or defaulting on more than $25 billion in performing restructured debt and triggering a domestic economic crisis.

Argentina tried to pay its restructured foreign bonds on 30 June, but was blocked by the court. It was left with a 30-day grace period to settle with the holdouts and avoid default. This period will be fraught for the immediate participants in the drama – Argentina, the holdouts, the restructured bond holders, trustees – but the implications of the US court decisions for the broader sovereign debt market are more significant. Thanks to these decisions, previously unenforceable debt contracts can now be enforced using a form of judicial boycott. While the indebted government might try to defy court orders, pay its restructured debt and use sovereign immunity to shield its property from creditor lawsuits, no financial institution with a presence in New York would risk dealing with it for fear of court sanctions. The defiant debtor can no longer live the normal financial life of a government in the global economy.

To be sure, both Elliott and Argentina are extreme in their own ways. Most creditors faced with an immune government cannot and do not chase it around the world for over a decade. They bargain hard, but ultimately accept the government’s debt restructuring offer. On the other hand, few countries have the resources or the political will to run from their creditors for decades, since without bankruptcy, the debt never goes away. Like most creditors, most governments prefer to settle. Elliott and Argentina chose to fight, and in the course of their fight have exposed the dubious foundation of the sovereign debt market. The court rulings from their fringe contest will apply to every country and every creditor henceforth.

This means that a country in debt trouble can no longer tell its creditors that if they refuse to restructure, they may go unpaid. Instead, holdout creditors stand a decent chance of holding the country and its restructured creditors to ransom unless and until they are paid in full. On the other hand, creditors contemplating a government’s restructuring offer must not only contemplate the size of their impending “haircut”, but also the possibility that they will never see their reduced payments, because a holdout might interrupt them. Even the bravest creditor would hesitate to jump in.

For now, contract reform remains the most promising and pragmatic way forward. The IMF and the London-based International Capital Market Association have separately proposed removing or modifying the pari passu clause, and adding robust majority-voting provisions in sovereign bonds. The new voting mechanism would operate across the entire stock of the distressed government’s bonds, so that if a supermajority of creditors supports the restructuring, holdouts with blocking positions in individual bond issues could not stay out of the deal and free-ride on the rest. Trustees, payment and clearing systems could speed up reform by conditioning access to their services on these and other contract changes, which makes them less vulnerable to being commandeered by holdout creditors.

In the long run, the market will surely adapt. This is small comfort to the poor countries, ordinary creditors, financial-market service providers and taxpayers in debtor and creditor countries alike, who will suffer through the fallout from Elliott and Argentina for years to come.

Author: Anna Gelpern is a professor at Georgetown University Law Centre and a non-resident senior fellow at Peterson Institute for International Economics.

 
One wonders how much of Ontario's debt is owned by Elliott...
 
Back
Top