• Thanks for stopping by. Logging in to a registered account will remove all generic ads. Please reach out with any questions or concerns.

Libertarians

Status
Not open for further replies.
Best of luck to your friend

As a libertarian, though, only point 1 (Public saftey) is an essential government function as far as I'm concerned.

Health care, infrastructure and education are all services which were delivered (and delivered well) by the private sector in the past, and could use a jolt of private sector competition to be revitalized and modernized today.
 
Thucydides said:
Best of luck to your friend

As a libertarian, though, only point 1 (Public saftey) is an essential government function as far as I'm concerned.

Health care, infrastructure and education are all services which were delivered (and delivered well) by the private sector in the past, and could use a jolt of private sector competition to be revitalized and modernized today.


In fact public safety and security are only recently in the full public (state) domain. For very long periods, in many (most?) societies the notion of the state having a monopoly on the use of force and a duty to keep people safe is very recent, indeed. Currency - the provision of a stable, useful money supply - seems, to me, to be one of the few areas in which the state (often the mini-state or statelet or principality or shire) has had a necessary and sometimes exclusive role.
 
Public saftey being a public "good" is indeed recent (Treaty of Westphalia, in fact), pre modern states were often characterized by private armies in the hands of feudal lords or their equivalents, and even personal retainers in the manner of Mafia enforcers in cities.

Of course, the ability to resist the demands of the Sovereign is what made premodern States so inefficient and often chaotic. Many modern "States" today still have militias, personal retainers and other armed actors who can defy the central government, with results that rival the efficiency of European polities of the 1400's...
 
A long article about the potential for Libertariansim and populism to be joined in the United States. I am not convinced, particularly since modern politics is highly tuned to stroke the base emotions of greed and envy amongst the voters (and politics is, after all, a means of allocating resources). Since Libertarians typically want you to keep what is yours but do not promise to use government power to "give" you goods and services paid out of other people's resources, their message isn't resonant with most voters.

OTOH, as governments and institutions evolve towards the Fascist Corporate State model, and political parties no longer have the answers to the issues that beset us, people will look to new models, structures and institutions which do provide shelter and solutions (Libertariansim as a social movement).

Part 1

http://townhall.com/tipsheet/conncarroll/2014/07/01/the-case-for-libertarian-populism-n1852602

The Case for Libertarian Populism
Conn Carroll | Jul 01, 2014
Conn Carroll
Share on Facebook 219 291 SHARES



Something is rotten in the United States of America.

Except for a brief surge of pride after the United States swore in its first black president in 2009, Americans have consistently told pollsters for more than a decade that they believe our country is heading in the wrong direction.

Neither party is offering an agenda that speaks to America’s concerns.

Democrats only want to grow the size and scope of the federal government at a time when America’s trust in its federal government has never been lower. Republicans want to cut taxes for the wealthy and help big corporations at a time when Americans believe federal government policies already favor the wealthy.

Americans want an alternative. An alternative that dismantles the power and wealth of special interests on the Left and the Right. An alternative that recognizes we can shrink the size and scope of the federal government in ways that benefit all Americans.

Some Republicans have recognized this need and are already advancing policies that move the party in this direction. But a wider agenda that adheres to these principles is possible. Let’s begin by examining where the two major parties have gone wrong.

THE CORPORATIST DEMOCRATIC PARTY
For liberals, the source of Americans’ unease is easily identifiable: income inequality.

It’s what brought the Occupy movement out into the streets. It’s the subject of a wildly popular new book by French socialist Thomas Piketty. And President Obama recently called it, “The defining issue of our time.”

How do liberals plan to fight income inequality? Through higher taxes on the wealthy and a slew of new government programs to redistribute the money, of course.

But progressives realized long ago that they needed deep-pocket partners to help run and popularize their treasured government programs. As Bill Scher of the liberal Campaign for America’s Future recently admitted in The New York Times, “The necessity of corporate support for, or at least acquiescence to, liberal policies is not a new development in the history of American liberalism. Indeed, it has been one of its hallmarks.”

More recently, this partnership of corporate and government interests was at the heart of President Obama’s signature domestic accomplishment, Obamacare.

Describing the legislation before passage, progressive journalist Glenn Greenwald noted the bill “forces millions of people to buy extremely inadequate products from the private health insurance industry regardless of whether they want it or, worse, whether they can afford it (even with some subsidies).”

“In other words,” Greenwald concluded, “it uses the power of government, the force of law, to give the greatest gift imaginable to this industry, tens of millions of coerced customers, many of whom will be truly burdened by having to turn their money over to these corporations.”

To his credit, MSNBC’s Chris Hayes wasn’t afraid to admit this governing model wasn’t limited to health care. “There’s a word for a governing philosophy that fuses the power of government and large corporations as a means of providing services and keeping the wheels of industry greased, and it’s a word that has begun to pop up among critics of everything from the TARP bailout to health care and cap and trade: corporatism.”

THE FAILING CORPORATIST MODEL
For decades now, corporatism has been a big winner for both the Democratic and Republican parties. In his recent book “Mass Flourishing,” 2006 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences winner Edmund Phelps explains why:

Corporatism satisfies a desire for security. People want security of consumption, security of jobs, and security of their economic status. Corporatism replaces the decentralized competition of the market with political control over the economy.

Corporatism allows CEOs to deliver near guaranteed steady profits while receiving fat salaries in return. It allows union leaders to promise lifetime jobs and generous benefits. And it allows politicians to take credit for every job, created or saved, by every company that takes a single dime from the government.

But corporatism no longer seems to be providing the peace of mind that it once did. According to a recent Pew poll, the percentage of Americans who describe themselves as middle class has fallen from 53 percent in 2008, to 44 percent today.

Meanwhile, the percentage of Americans who describe themselves as “upper-class” has also shrunk from 21 percent to 15 percent over that same time. Only the ranks of the self- described “lower-class” are growing. Their numbers have almost doubled from 25 percent in 2008 to 40 percent today.

And a quick look at the data shows that American unease is completely justified. During the first four years of the current recovery (beginning in June 2009), the U.S. economy grew just 10 percent. By contrast, over the first four years of the Reagan recovery (beginning in November 1982), the economy grew by 20 percent.

Job growth during the recent recovery has also been anemic. During the first four years of the Reagan recovery in the 1980s, 11.5 million jobs were created. Fast forward to today, and just 5.3 million net new jobs were created over the same time frame.

Worse, median household income has actually fallen, from $53,285 in 2009, to $51,017 in 2012 (the most recent data available). By contrast, during that same time frame in the ‘80s, median household income shot up from $46,082 in 1982, to $48,063 in 1985 (all of the above income numbers are in constant 2012 dollars).

WHY CORPORATISM FAILS
Corporatism can, and often does, thrive. But only for a limited time. Eventually the tools Big Business and Big Government use to maintain their monopoly on power, undermine economic growth.

In order to maintain their size and stability, corporations use government power to keep new competitors out of the market. They pay lobbyists to manipulate the tax code in a way that benefits their business model. And they help shape complex regulatory schemes that require thousands of billable hours to sort through, thus raising the price of entry.

One would expect to see new firm formation plummet as an economy becomes more corporatist, and that is exactly what has happened in the United States. According to Hoover Institution analysis of U.S. Census Bureau data, the annual rate of new business formation is almost 30 percent lower today than it was in the 1980s.

And the American people know the partnership between Big Government and Big Business is making their lives worse.

An October 2013 CNN poll found that while 60 percent of Americans agree with the statement that “the government is trying to do too many things that should be left to individuals and businesses,” just 35 percent said “that government should do more to solve our country’s problems.”

A September 2013 Gallup poll found that 60 percent of Americans agree with the statement that the federal government has “too much power” while just 32 percent said it has “the right amount.”

And according to Pew, not only is trust in the federal government at an all-time low (and anger at an all-time high), but for the first time since Pew has been asking the question, a majority of Americans (53 percent) believe the federal government is an overall threat to their personal rights.
 
Part 2

http://townhall.com/tipsheet/conncarroll/2014/07/01/the-case-for-libertarian-populism-n1852602

CUTTING TAXES FOR THE RICH ISN’T ENOUGH
But if Americans are so skeptical about the size and scope of the current federal government, and they want to see it scaled back, then why did they re-elect Obama in 2012?

Because they don’t believe the current Republican Party cares about them.

If you look at the 2012 exit polls, you’ll see that the very same electorate that re-elected Obama by a 51 percent to 47 percent margin, also told exit pollsters, by an even larger 51 percent to 43 percent margin, that “government is doing too many things better left to businesses and individuals.”

Republicans won the argument over the size and scope of the federal government. But Obama won the argument over “who cares about people like me.”

Obama and Romney mostly split voters who chose their candidate based on who “shares my values,” who “is a strong leader,” and who “has a vision for the future.” But among those voters who cast their ballot based on which candidate “cares about people like me,” Obama walloped Romney 81 percent to 21 percent.

And while Romney actually won among voters who earned between $50,000 and $100,000 a year (by 52 percent to 36 percent), and among voters who earned more than $100,000 a year (by 54 percent to 44 percent), he was slaughtered by voters who made less than $50,000 a year (60 percent to 38 percent). And those voters made up 41 percent of the electorate in 2012.

Romney lost because far too many working Americans simply did not believe he cared about them. Which is only fair since Romney flat out told CNN’s Soledad O’Brien, “I’m not concerned about the very poor.”

If Republicans are ever going to win the White House again, they are going to have to find a way to convince working Americans that they care about them, and that their policies will benefit them.

THE LIBERTARIAN POPULIST ALTERNATIVE
At the same time that American distrust in the federal government is at record highs, there is also a strong populist streak running through the American people.

Sixty-four percent of Americans recently told ABC News that federal government policies currently favor the wealthy, while 57 percent said they’d support policies to try to reduce the wealth gap in this country.

And according to Bloomberg, 64 percent of Americans believe the country no longer offers everyone an equal chance to get ahead, while an even larger 68 percent believe the income gap between rich and poor is growing. Additionally, 52 percent of Americans think the government should redistribute wealth “by heavy taxes on the rich,” while just 45 percent say it should not.

Republicans should not ignore these populist impulses. Rather, they should embrace them because the public is largely right. The current corporatist policies coming from Washington do favor the wealthy.

It is harder to get ahead in this country when entire sectors of the economy are controlled by a few highly regulated, government-favored firms. The tax code does contain far too many loopholes for the rich and powerful that subsequently drive up tax burdens on the rest of America.

By trying to do too much, and often advantaging the wealthy and politically connected in the process, the federal government has become a force for growing inequality and economic immobility.

Republicans need to find ways they can help the everyday lives of average Americans by cutting the size and scope of the federal government.

A LIBERTARIAN POPULIST AGENDA
The federal government will spend $3.5 trillion in 2014 administering an unknown number of government programs through more than 500 government agencies using almost 2.8 million employees.

Not every wasteful program or agency can be identified in this short space, and it would be next to impossible to eliminate them all at once. But Republicans can push a populist agenda that would slowly roll back the size and scope of the federal government thus giving all Americans more freedom to prosper. Here are just some areas where they could start.

GIVE EVERY WORKING AMERICAN A RAISE
If you wanted to design a tax that both made working Americans poorer and killed jobs in the process, the 12.4 percent Social Security payroll tax is exactly what it would look like.

Almost one quarter of all federal government revenue ($673 billion) was raised by the Social Security payroll tax in 2013, and it is one of the most regressive tax policies the federal government administers.

The only policies possibly more regressive than the payroll tax are some of the more than $1.4 trillion in tax expenditures buried in the federal government’s 70,000-page-plus tax code.

“Tax expenditures,” the Congressional Budget Office explains, “are generally designed to further societal goals.” But, the CBO continues, “by providing benefits to particular activities, entities, or groups of people, tax expenditures increase the size and scope of federal involvement in the economy.”

And tax expenditures not only increase the size and scope of the federal government, but they do so in a way that predominantly benefits the wealthiest Americans. Almost 90 percent of the state and local tax deduction, for example, goes to households making more than $100,000 a year. Seventy-seven percent of the mortgage interest deduction and 75 percent of the real estate property deduction also go to households with incomes over $100,000.

If Republicans proposed limiting the mortgage interest deduction to just households with incomes below $200,000, and they eliminated the mortgage deduction for second homes, as well as the state and local tax deduction, the real property tax deduction, the state and local bond interest exclusion, and the investment income on life insurance exclusion, all of which predominately benefit wealthy households, they then could also cut the employee side of the payroll tax in half without adding a dime to the deficit.

Not only would that mean a smaller tax code and a less intrusive federal government, but it would also mean an extra $1,500 a year in take home pay for the average American household.

 
Part 3

http://townhall.com/tipsheet/conncarroll/2014/07/01/the-case-for-libertarian-populism-n1852602

END THE DRUG WAR
Conservatives know that the best weapon any community has against poverty is the millenniums-old institution of marriage. Unfortunately in far too many communities today, marriage has all but disappeared.

According to the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, more than 72 percent of African-American children are born out of wedlock. And it is not because black men do not want to be fathers. They most certainly do. The CDC reports that when black men do live in the same home as their children, they are just as involved in their children’s lives as other fathers, if not more.

Unfortunately far too few black men are living with their biological children and the federal government is a big reason why. The federal government’s War on Drugs has put far too many non-violent young men behind bars. The Bureau of Justice Statistics estimates that almost 1 in 5 black men has served time in prison. And a recent University of South Carolina study found that nearly half of all black males have been arrested by the time they turn 23.

Jail time not only rips black men from the communities that desperately need them, it also makes it harder for them to provide for a family once they’ve paid their debt to society. Convicts have higher unemployment rates and receive lower wages than those without criminal records.

Worse, as Manhattan Institute John McWhorter explains, the War on Drugs “discourages young black men from seeking legal employment.”

“Because the illegality of drugs keeps the prices high,” McWhorter notes, “there are high salaries to be made in selling them. This makes selling drugs a standing tempting alternative to seeking lower-paying legal employment. The result is usually spells in jail, as well as failure to build the job skills for legal employment that serve as a foundation for productive existence in middle and later life.”

By ending the War on Drugs, the federal government would not only return much-needed human capital to beleaguered communities, it would also be a fiscal win for taxpayers as well. According to the Cato Institute, decriminalizing drugs would reduce federal government spending by $15.6 billion and would free up $25.7 billion in state and local tax dollars as well.

Yes, marijuana, cocaine, and heroin are all still hellish substances that we as a society should discourage people from using. But jail has proved to be an ineffective, and even harmful, method of sending that signal.

As William F. Buckley explained back in 1996, “It is our judgment that the War on Drugs has failed, that it is diverting intelligent energy away from how to deal with the problem of addiction, that it is wasting our resources, and that it is encouraging civil, judicial, and penal procedures associated with police states.”

Bottom line, it is far past time for small-government conservatives to stop supporting the failed War on Drugs.

STOP PENALIZING MARRIAGE
Incarcerating young men is not the only way the federal government makes it harder for Americans to get, and stay, married. The federal tax code, and every means tested welfare program, also makes marriage harder, particularly for low-income couples.

Take a low-income working mother who currently qualifies for the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (food stamps), Temporary Assistance to Needy Families, Medicaid, and the Earned Income Tax Credit. If she marries a man with no job, or cohabits with a man who is working, then her benefits do not change.

But if she were to marry a man with a job, even a low-income job, her SNAP, TANF, and EITC benefits are all likely to be reduced and she could be forced out of Medicaid entirely. This can cause a major financial strain on a young low-income couple trying to build a life together.

One study found that the median married working poor couple loses 12 percent of their household income from these penalties after they get married.

Most wealthy couples would face a strained marriage if 12 percent of their income suddenly disappeared. For working poor families, it is hard to see how such a huge financial hit would not contribute to divorce.

Congress must stop punishing the working poor for getting married. Married couples should be allowed to keep their previously qualified for benefits through the first few years of marriage.

END THE HEALTH INSURANCE MANDATES
Obamacare’s individual mandate, the requirement forcing all Americans to buy government-approved health insurance, has always been among the most unpopular portions of health care reform. Republicans should push to repeal it entirely.

Far too few pollsters ask about the individual mandate on a regular basis, but when they do, American opposition is strong. For example, in November 2013, ABC News measured overall opposition to Obamacare at 57 percent. But when asked if they “support or oppose ... requiring nearly all Americans to have health insurance or pay a fine,” 65 percent of Americans told ABC they opposed the mandate.

A month later ABC News specifically asked if the individual mandate should be delayed a year and a full 60 percent of Americans agreed that it should.

And that is not the only mandate that is politically vulnerable. The employer mandate has already proved so unworkable that the Obama administration has twice delayed its implementation.

Even Obamacare’s biggest proponent, progressive commentator Ezra Klein, admitted the employer mandate, “gives employers a reason to have fewer full-time workers, and fewer low-income workers.”

In other words, Obamacare’s employer mandate is a job killer. Republicans should force Democrats to defend this unemployment-machine at every turn.

Once the individual and employer mandates are eliminated, Obamacare will begin to collapse under its own weight. Republicans must be ready to step forward with policies to minimize the pain.

They can start by ending two government created monopolies partially responsible for driving up health care costs: the ban on purchasing insurance across state lines and the prohibition against non-doctors providing health care.

Once Americans can purchase plans from any state in the country, and are allowed to buy care from nurse practitioners, physician assistants, and other non-physician medical professionals, the cost of health insurance should fall.

Slowly phasing out the employer-provided health care tax deduction, which also predominantly benefits wealthy Americans, while using that revenue to pay for a standard health care tax credit for all Americans, would also increase competition and lower costs.
 
Part 4

http://townhall.com/tipsheet/conncarroll/2014/07/01/the-case-for-libertarian-populism-n1852602

END SECURITY THEATER
If you’ve ever seen an 85-year-old grandmother forced out of her wheelchair for a pat down, or forced your own crying 3-year-old to put their beloved stuffed animal through an X-ray machine, then you already know that there is perhaps no better example of Big Government’s wasteful, intrusive, and stupid bloat than the Transportation Security Administration.

And the man who created the TSA agrees.

“The whole program has been hijacked by bureaucrats,” former-Rep. John Mica (R-FL), the author of the legislation that created the TSA, told Human Events in 2011. “It mushroomed into an army,” Mica continued. “They’ve failed to actually detect any threat in 10 years. The whole thing is a complete fiasco.”

Before 9/11, just 16,500 private workers maintained security at our nation’s airports. Today, the TSA employs 62,000 people at a cost of $7.9 billion to taxpayers. And there is zero evidence they are providing any real security.

Instead of lighting $8 billion in taxpayer money on fire every year in the name of security, Congress should outright abolish the TSA and return responsibility for security back to private airports.

STOP SUBSIDIZING DEBT
Americans are rightly concerned about the size of current federal deficits. But as bad as our growing government debt is, household debt is even more destructive for most Americans.

While the federal government can almost always print or borrow more money, the same is not true for American households. When hard times hit, indebted families are forced to cut spending. Not only does food, entertainment, and other consumer spending fall, but the capital needed to turn an idea into new jobs isn’t there; moves to other parts of the country with better job prospects are harder to make; and it is difficult to invest in education or job training without going even deeper in debt.

As a result, high levels of household debt lead to weaker economic recoveries. A recent analysis of new data from the Great Depression found that states with higher debt-to-income ratios recovered at much slower rates than states with lower pre-Depression levels of household debt.

So it shouldn’t surprise us that the weakest economic recovery since the Great Depression just happened to coincide with the highest debt-to-disposable-income ratio ever recorded in American history at about 130 percent. During the much stronger Reagan recovery, the household debt ratio was less than half as high.

Many conservatives might say that those who over-borrowed deserve their fate. If they spent too much, that is their problem. But this perfectly valid intuition ignores the role the federal government played encouraging Americans to borrow more.

Credit card and auto loan debt, which are not subsidized by the federal government, made up just 13 percent of all household debt before the recession and still do today. Mortgage debt however, which is heavily subsidized by the federal government, made up 78 percent of all household debt before the crisis, and has fallen only 4 points, to 74 percent of all household debt today.

But while mortgage debt may be falling slightly, the federal government’s other major debt subsidy program, student debt, has exploded. Before the crisis, Americans owed just over $600 billion in student debt, or just 5 percent of all household debt. Today, Americans owe more than $1 trillion in student debt, which currently makes up almost 9 percent of all household debt.

Combined, government subsidized debt (both mortgage and student) now makes up 83 percent of all household debt. To the extent that Americans do have a borrowing problem, the federal government is largely to blame.

Capping the aforementioned mortgage interest deduction would be a good start to getting the federal government out of the debt-subsidy business, but more must be done, especially on the student loan front.

In addition to slowly phasing out the student loan program and offering more direct student aid instead (paid for by eliminating existing ineffective federal education/training programs), Republicans should break up the college accreditation monopolies that are currently strangling higher education innovation.

By allowing states, instead of the federal government, to determine which institutions are eligible for federal aid, Republicans can unleash a wave of education innovation that should bring down the cost of college for almost everyone.

Yes, Yale and Harvard will always be exclusive and expensive. But there is no reason every American should be tied to a 19th century model for post-secondary education. Internships, apprenticeships, coding academies, online classes, and competency-based learning are just some of the ways Americans can better prepare for entering the workforce without wasting four years and tens of thousands of dollars on a college campus.

BREAK UP THE BANKS
No federal government response to the 2008 financial crisis was more unpopular than the Troubled Asset Relief Program, more commonly known as TARP, or the Wall Street bailout.

While the federal government did end up making a profit on the bank portion of TARP (but lost money on the auto bailout), Americans are right to view the TARP program, and the policy mistakes that led to it, with great skepticism.

But, contrary to the liberal narrative, it was not free markets or deregulation that allowed our nation’s financial institutions to become too big to fail. It was Big Government.

Just as the government-sponsored entities Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae always benefited from the belief that Washington would bail them out if they got in trouble, our nation’s largest banks also benefited from a similar perception. As a result of this implied-bailout-guarantee, large institutions were able to borrow capital at lower rates than their smaller competitors.

In addition, it was government regulation, not markets, (specifically the Basel Accord capital requirements) that created the high demand for mortgage securities in the first place. And finally, the credit-rating agencies that failed to accurately measure the true risk in mortgage-backed securities did so because they themselves are a government-created monopoly.

In 1970, the five largest banks in the United States controlled just 17 percent of all bank assets, while the nation’s 2,500 smallest banks controlled 46 percent of the assets. But by 2010 the nation’s five biggest banks controlled 52 percent of all bank assets, while the nation’s smallest 5,700 banks controlled just 16 percent of the assets.

President Obama’s Dodd-Frank regulations have only made the problem worse. Weighing in at just under 850 pages, and with more than 14,000 pages of regulations written so far, Dodd-Frank has been a huge stimulus program for Wall Street law firms and the mega banks they work for.

Small community banks, however, simply can’t afford the millions of billable hours it takes to make sense of Dodd-Frank. This is why JP Morgan CEO Jamie Dimon affectionately described Dodd-Frank as a “bigger moat” that helps protect JP Morgan from competition.

As a result of all this regulatory complexity, the nation’s largest banks now control an even larger percentage of the nation’s assets than when Dodd-Frank became law. Unless we want to suffer through another financial crisis, and the double-digit unemployment rates that go with it, we must break up the nation’s largest banks now.

Many on the Left have been pushing to break up the banks for years, preferring that a new or existing government agency nationalize the banks before selling them off in smaller pieces.

But such interventionist and disruptive tactics are not necessary. Since Big Government created the Big Banks, a smaller government should be able to right-size them.

Republicans should push to make all banks with more than $50 billion in assets ineligible for the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation program. Then, either the megabanks would shrink voluntarily or the American people would more likely take their money elsewhere.

A NEW REPUBLICAN PARTY
In 1976, President Ford narrowly lost the White House to former-Gov. Jimmy Carter, 48 percent to 50 percent. Carter’s narrow margin was secured by lower-income Americans who gave Carter an overwhelming 62 percent to 38 percent margin (two points worse than Romney’s 2012 showing).

Just two months later, on February 6, 1977, a former-governor of California told a packed hotel ballroom in Washington, D.C., that the Republican Party would have to reinvent itself if it was going to survive.

“The New Republican Party I envision will not be, and cannot be, one limited to the country club-Big Business image that, for reasons both fair and unfair, it is burdened with today,” this former-governor said.

“The New Republican Party I am speaking about is going to have room for the man and the woman in the factories, for the farmer, for the cop on the beat, and the millions of Americans who may never have thought of joining our party before, but whose interests coincide with those represented by principled Republicanism.”

That former-governor was, of course, President Reagan. And in the 1980 election, not only did Reagan beat Carter 51 percent to 41 percent, but he cut Ford’s 24 point loss among the lowest- income Americans to just 10 points.

Republicans can win significant votes from every demographic. There are millions of Americans who share the Republican Party’s limited government vision but just don’t vote for them because Republicans have a reputation for supporting the rich and not caring about the poor.

By pursuing an agenda and crafting a message that demonstrates how a smaller government can help the everyday lives of average Americans, especially those with lower-incomes who suffer from regressive payroll taxes and government subsidized debt, Republicans can win elections in presidential years again.
 
On reflection I decided this is the most appropriate venue for this article, since it shows how many of the traditional political alignments are being crosscut by emerging institutions, business and technology. Canada should be facing similar issues as business like Uber and Lyft penetrate the Canadian market, or upstart companies like Tesla or Amazon.ca bypass traditional market channels (Tesla is under injunctions in several US States because they do not sell their cars through dealerships, something car dealers are fighting against in their State Legislatures).

This fits my thesis of Libertarianism as a Social Movement, rather than a political movement. As a BTY, I am working with some friends to see how we can incorporate these issues into London's upcoming municipal election and make candidates speak to these issues.

http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2014/07/07/grover-norquist-thinks-republicans-can-ride-uber-to-power-in-urban-areas-thats-probably-a-stretch/

Grover Norquist thinks Republicans can ride Uber to power in urban areas. That’s probably a stretch.
   
By Emily Badger July 7 

Abdul Sami, 51, protests with other commercial drivers with the app-based, ride-sharing company Uber against working conditions outside the company's office in Santa Monica, California June 24, 2014. (REUTERS/Lucy Nicholson)
The "sharing economy" is so interesting primarily because it has cracked open all kinds of fault lines, where it's often difficult to tell which side the good guys reside on. We have taxi drivers pitted against amateur chauffeurs, hotel chains against homeowners, incumbent businesses with legitimate gripes against "micro-entrepreneurs" trying to make money in ways regulation never envisioned.

There's a clash between entrenched laws and technological change, between officials who support new ideas and regulators charged with enforcing older ones. There's a tension between public safety and consumer demand, between tax revenue and new economic models, between affordable housing stock and housing that's more affordable when the person living in it can rent out her den.

In its short life, however, the sharing economy has seldom reflected a clear schism between Republicans and Democrats — an argument Grover Norquist tries to make today in a provocative opinion piece for Reuters. Companies like Uber, he writes with Americans for Tax Reform colleague Patrick Gleason, can help the GOP gain control of cities where they've been all but absent for years. Their logic:

Yet despite the Democrats’ urban dominance, cities may soon be up for grabs. For the party’s refusal to embrace the innovative technology and disruptive businesses that have greatly improved city life presents a challenge to Democrats — and an opportunity for Republicans.

Democrats are facing a tough choice. A big part of their base is the unions now facing off against such disruptive innovations as Uber, Lyft, Airbnb and charter schools. Do Democrats support the regulations pushed by taxi and other unions that help to protect the status quo but can also stifle competition? Or do they embrace innovative technologies and businesses that expand transportation options, create jobs and are increasingly welcomed by another key Democratic constituency: urban dwellers, particularly young urban dwellers?

Norquist and Gleason are right that there will no doubt be political fallout from the sharing economy. I recently met a number of cab drivers in Chicago who pledged to me that they would fight against the reelection of Mayor Rahm Emanuel because of his support for services like Uber and Lyft there. But it's not at all clear that this fallout will favor Republicans.

Norquist and Gleason describe with a broad brush "liberal and progressive resistance to Uber and its ilk," as if all resistance were liberal, and all liberals were united in their opposition. In fact, Emanuel called for and signed new regulations in Chicago that legalize UberX and Lyft. Seattle's new mayor, Ed Murray, just negotiated new regulations that these same companies support. He's a Democrat. New York Attorney General Eric Schneiderman has fought Airbnb. He's a Democrat. Colorado Gov. John Hickenlooper signed the first state bill (sponsored by Democrats) clearing the way for UberX and Lyft. He's a Democrat.

New Pittsburgh Mayor Bill Peduto backs similar regulation — he's a Democrat — but the state's public utilities commission has been threatening these companies anyway. Arizona Gov. Jan Brewer vetoed a pro-Uber bill (sponsored by a Republican state representative) that she said did not do enough to protect consumer safety. She's a Republican.

Norquist and Gleason cite the example that "June began with Virginia Governor Terry McAuliffe’s administration sending a cease and desist letter to Uber." But they don't mention that, by early July, Virginia was already reversing course.

Last year, the U.S. House committee on small business held an initial hearing on the sharing economy, and I watched Democrats and Republicans take turns rewording the same questions about what the government could do to help. Partisan theater didn't seem to occur to anyone. And consumers show a similar ambivalence. For some, the sharing economy is about progressive virtues (community!), for others libertarian values (less regulation!). Marco Rubio is a fan of Uber. So is Gavin Newsom.

The point here isn't that Democrats are all supporters of the sharing economy. It's that support isn't as contingent on ideology as Norquist and Gleason suggest. And the political lines are definitely not so tidy as to suggest that Republicans can leverage liberals' "refusal to embrace the innovative technology" to sweep back into favor with urban voters. There's room here for Democrats to acknowledge that markets can partly regulate themselves — with the help of technology — in ways that weren't possible in the past; there's room for Republicans to acknowledge that we need laws mandating commercial auto insurance anyway.

We've heard a lot from Democrats on these issues precisely because they're playing out in cities so far. And, inevitably, elected Democrats like Rahm Emanuel will be forced to take positions that will please some core constituents at the expense of others. The tension between unions and young consumers is particularly compelling. Republicans should absolutely jump into that fray. They haven't found a lot of reasons to talk to urban voters lately — if people like Norquist think this is one, that's great.

But the fact that this debate isn't neatly drawn into liberal and conservative camps is a testament to the policy issues raised by the sharing economy: They're incredibly, incredibly messy. They also aren't purely about big-picture ideological battles over less regulation or more union power, the kind of divisive themes that animate federal policy debates. They're about the gritty details of auto insurance policies and tax receipts and access for disabled consumers. That's not the stuff of pithy partisan slogans.
 
Throughout organized history, those who have made it and have control over an industry try very hard to prevent others from taking a piece of that pie and will defend/attack any threat. Sometimes that response is driven by a duty for those that work for them, other times it's to guard their own rice bowel, no matter how big.
 
There are some good arguments being made over regulating companies such as Uber and Lyft from the public safety and Tax revenue side of the equation. And it's not just to the advantage of the taxi drivers, but also the drivers who sign up with Uber  or Lyft that benefit from the regulations.

There was a story on the local news here about a driver for one of the companies who was told specifically by a company rep that he would be covered by a supplemental policy that the company offers when he is providing services for that company. When he found himself in need of that insurance, he was told that this was not the case, and that his own insurance would cover him. But because he was using his vehicle for commercial purposes, his own insurer denied coverage as he did not have commercial insurance or a commercial chauffeur's license.

But having regulations where drivers and vehicles have to meet minimum standards for equipment, insurance coverage, and qualifications only makes sense.
 
>But having regulations ... only makes sense.

That's the thin edge of every wedge currently holding things up.  "A" story, or even a handful of stories, should not be a trigger for nationwide hand-wringing and legislation.
 
Brad Sallows said:
>But having regulations ... only makes sense.

That's the thin edge of every wedge currently holding things up.  "A" story, or even a handful of stories, should not be a trigger for nationwide hand-wringing and legislation.

No one is really looking at it from the aspect of the driver's protection. The majority of jurisdictions here are issuing cease and desist orders based on non-conformance to taxi regulations and / or non payment of taxes. I just thought that this was an interesting spin on it from another angle.

And to be clear, it is the ride sharing service such as Uber-X that is being challenged. Uber's original service where you have dedicated drivers in upscale vehicles is not being subjected to the same level of attention, and have been more accepted.

 
The bottom line is that it's eating into "guild" turf; any rationalization to retain the crony capitalist structure will be sought by those whose interests lie with the "guild".

I read an observation/hypothesis/speculation recently to the effect that the mean time between some value-enhancing innovation and its regulatory capture and strangulation seems to be decreasing.
 
Brad Sallows said:
I read an observation/hypothesis/speculation recently to the effect that the mean time between some value-enhancing innovation and its regulatory capture and strangulation seems to be decreasing.

"Who is John Galt?"

 
Crony capitalism has been around for a long time, and the growth of parasitic bureaucracies is also a long standing issue. It should be no surprise that the States which limited crony capitalism and bureaucracies in the 1600's did much better than those that didn't...

http://washingtonexaminer.com/fighting-parasitic-bureaucracies-and-crony-capitalism/article/2551305?custom_click=rss&utm_source=twitterfeed&utm_medium=twitter

Fighting parasitic bureaucracies and crony capitalism
BY MICHAEL BARONE | JULY 27, 2014 | 6:00 PM

“Pare down the parasitic fringe” of government. “Favor a gospel of work” instead of aristocratic entitlement. “Rationalize finance” and “reverse the Parkinson’s law of bureaucracy.”

All that sounds like rhetoric from the Tea Party or reform conservatives who assail what they call crony capitalism.

But it's not a contemporary criticism. Those are phrases from a long essay, written more than half a century ago, by the British historian H. R. Trevor-Roper, entitled “The General Crisis of the Seventeenth Century.”

In his plummy prose, Trevor-Roper sought to explain why revolutions or revolts of varying sorts broke out in the British Isles, France, Spain, Italy and Germany in the years between 1640 and 1660.

He was especially eager to refute Marxist historians’ claims that these were the necessary predicate to what their master proclaimed would be the inevitable and beneficent communist revolutions that unaccountably had not yet occurred.

Trevor-Roper argues that the growing nation-states of the 1500s, engorged with New World silver and inflationary currencies, built up large bureaucracies that stifled trade and manufactures. The Counter-Reformation Catholic Church had a similar effect.

These bureaucracies were particularly expensive because rulers gave their favorites “the right to exploit their fellow subjects,” with monopolies in particular commodities and grants of land they could profitably dispose of. Crony capitalism was squeezing out a potentially productive private sector.

It's not hard to see some resemblance to America today. The federal bureaucracy head count is not significantly larger than it was 50 years ago. But the federal impact is much greater, through entitlement programs, subcontracted welfare provisions and regulation that favors entrenched interests.

Thus the Dodd-Frank Act gives favored financial institutions too-big-to-fail status that enables them to muscle aside potential competitors. The Export-Import Bank provides special favors to a few giant corporations. But there are few loans to start-up businesses.

Government subsidization of health care, even before Obamacare, and of higher education creates huge dysfunctional bureaucracies that vacuum up supposed benefits to patients and students.

Agricultural subsidies and price-fixing, “green energy” programs, laws like the Jones Act and Davis-Bacon that restrict work to unionized firms — all siphon off money and resources from the productive private sector to politically well-positioned special interests.

Trevor-Roper points out that princely states and the Counter-Reformation Church proliferated “hatcheries which turned out the superfluous bureaucrats,” as many colleges and universities do today.

State and local governments, often the captives of public sector unions, pay higher-than-private-sector wages to bureaucrats and teachers and make pension promises that will burden the productive economy for generations.

Seventeenth century European reformers had another model in mind, the prosperous Renaissance city-states of Italy and Flanders, many of which were squeezed out of business by nation-states.

After 1660 the nation-states that pared back bureaucracies and allowed room for such trading cities to operate -- England, Holland and, for a while, France -- flourished, while Spain, Italy and Germany mostly languished.

Americans today, thanks to our federal system, have models available too. Texas, with its low taxes and sensibly light regulation, has a booming multi-sector economy with high job creation. Fracking technology, on private lands not owned by the government, has increased oil and gas production far above levels government agencies and big corporations predicted.

Some conservatives nostalgic for the Reagan revolution insist that the key to sparking private sector growth is cutting high tax rates. But rates aren't so high today, and crony capitalism, particularly since the 2008 financial crisis, has metastasized far beyond 1980s levels.

Today the reform conservatives and Tea Partiers are moving, hesitantly and unevenly, on the path toward clearing away impediments to growth and paring down what Trevor-Roper calls “the monstrous parasite.”

The bipartisan coalition that has supported farm bills has broken down. Proposals to raise the gas tax to fund transportation are going nowhere. House Republican leaders are talking seriously about refusing to reauthorize the Export-Import Bank.

Reform conservatives have called for measures to help struggling Americans without political connections work their way up. And last week, House Budget Chairman Paul Ryan unveiled a 73-page antipoverty agenda going beyond his previous tax cut and entitlement reform proposals.

Such proposals are emerging without any institutional economically motivated base. It’s starting to look something like what Trevor-Roper saw in the seventeenth century: an “indeterminate, unpolitical, but highly sensitive miscellany of men” mutinying “against the vast, oppressive, ever-extending apparatus of parasitic bureaucracy.”

Conditions are becoming unbearable to more and more people, and they are looking for an "out". Most people do not see a solution in politics or the political class, hence "Libertarianism as a social movement" in response.
 
Niall Ferguson has a very interesting article in "The American Interest" on the challenge of Networks to the current Hierarchies that define today's power structures. As the existing hierarchies and institutions are less and less able to adapt to the changing economic, demographic and technological landscapes, they will eventually be supplemented and replaced by new organizations and institutions which can provide functionality in these new environments (Libertarianism as a social movement). As you can expect, the existing hierarchies provide a huge payoff for existing elites, and they will fight to the last taxpayer to maintain their positions of privilege and power:

Part 1

http://www.the-american-interest.com/articles/2014/06/09/networks-and-hierarchies/

Networks and Hierarchies

By Niall Ferguson

Published June 9, 2014 in The American Interest

Has political hierarchy in the form of the state met its match in today’s networked world?

Fritz Lang’s silent movie classic Metropolis (1927) depicts the downfall of a hierarchical megacity. Metropolis is a city of skyscrapers. At the top, in their penthouse C-suites, lives a wealthy elite led by the autocrat Joh Fredersen. Down below, in subterranean factories, the proletariat toils. After he witnesses an industrial accident, Fredersen’s playboy son is awakened to the squalor and danger of working-class life. The upshot is a violent revolution and a self-inflicted if inadvertent disaster: When the workers smash the power generators, their own living quarters are flooded because the water pumps fail. Today, Metropolis is perhaps best remembered for the iconic female robot that becomes the doppelgänger of the heroine, Maria. Yet it is better understood as a metaphor for history’s fundamental dialectic between hierarchies and networks.

Lang said the film was inspired by his first visit to New York. To his eyes, the skyscrapers of Manhattan were the perfect architectural expression of a hierarchical and unequal society. Contemporaries, notably the right-wing media magnate Alfred Hugenberg, detected a communist subtext, though Lang’s wife, who co-wrote the screenplay, was a radical German nationalist who later joined the Nazi Party. Viewed today, the film transcends the political ideologies of the mid-20th century. With its multiple religious allusions, culminating in an act of redemption, Metropolis is modernity mythologized. The central question it poses is as relevant today as it was then: How can an urbanized, technologically advanced society avoid disaster when its social consequences are profoundly anti-egalitarian?

There is, perhaps, an even more profound question in the subtext of Lang’s film: Who wins, the hierarchy or the network? The greatest threat to the hierarchical social order of Metropolis is posed not by flooding but by a clandestine conspiracy among the workers. Nothing infuriates Fredersen more than the realization that this conspiracy was hatched in the catacombs beneath the city without his knowledge.

In today’s terms, the hierarchy is not a single city but the state itself, the vertically structured super-polity that evolved out of the republics and monarchies of early modern Europe. Though not the most populous nation in the world, the United States is certainly the world’s most powerful state, despite the limits imposed by checks (to lobbyists) and balances (as in bank). Its nearest rival, the People’s Republic of China, is usually seen as a profoundly different kind of state, for while the United States has two major parties and a gaggle of tiny ones, the People’s Republic has one and only one. American government is founded on the separation of powers, not least the independence of its judiciary; the PRC subordinates law, such as it has evolved in China over the centuries, to the dictates of the Communist Party.

Yet both states are republics, with roughly comparable vertical structures of administration and not wholly dissimilar concentrations of power in the hands of the central government. Economically, the two systems are certainly converging, with China looking ever more to market signals and incentives, while the United States keeps increasing the statutory and regulatory power of government over producers and consumers. And, to an extent that disturbs civil libertarians on both Left and Right, the U.S. government exerts control and practices surveillance over its citizens in ways that are functionally closer to contemporary China than to the America of the Founding Fathers.

To all the world’s states, democratic and undemocratic alike, the new informational, commercial, and social networks of the internet age pose a profound challenge, the scale of which is only gradually becoming apparent. First email achieved a dramatic improvement in the ability of ordinary citizens to communicate with one another. Then the internet came to have an even greater impact on the ability of citizens to access information. The emergence of search engines marked a quantum leap in this process. The advent of laptops, smartphones, and other portable devices then emancipated electronic communication from the desktop. With the explosive growth of social networks came another great leap, this time in the ability of citizens to share information and ideas.

It was not immediately obvious how big a challenge all this posed to the established state. There was a great deal of cheerful talk about the ways in which the information technology revolution would promote “smart” or “joined-up” government, enhancing the state’s ability to interact with citizens. However, the efforts of Anonymous, Wikileaks and Edward Snowden to disrupt the system of official secrecy, directed mainly against the U.S. government, have changed everything. In particular, Snowden’s revelations have exposed the extent to which Washington was seeking to establish a parasitical relationship with the key firms that operate the various electronic networks, acquiring not only metadata but sometimes also the actual content of vast numbers of phone calls and messages. Techniques of big-data mining, developed initially for commercial purposes, have been adapted to the needs of the National Security Agency.

The most recent, and perhaps most important, network challenge to hierarchy comes with the advent of virtual currencies and payment systems like Bitcoin. Since ancient times, states have reaped considerable benefits from monopolizing or at least regulating the money created within their borders. It remains to be seen how big a challenge Bitcoin poses to the system of national fiat currencies that has evolved since the 1970s and, in particular, how big a challenge it poses to the “exorbitant privilege” enjoyed by the United States as the issuer of the world’s dominant reserve (and transaction) currency. But it would be unwise to assume, as some do, that it poses no challenge at all.

Clashes between hierarchies and networks are not new in history; on the contrary, there is a sense in which they are history. Indeed, the course of history can be thought of as the net result of human interactions along four axes.

The first of these is time. The arrow of time can move in only one direction, even if we have become increasingly sophisticated in our conceptualization and measurement of its flight. The second is nature: Nature means in this context the material or environmental constraints over which we still have little control, notably the laws of physics, the geography and geology of the planet, its climate and weather, the incidence of disease, our own evolution as a species, our fertility, and the bell curves of our abilities as individuals in a series of normal distributions. The third is networks. Networks are the spontaneously self-organizing, horizontal structures we form, beginning with knowledge and the various “memes” and representations we use to communicate it. These include the patterns of migration and miscegenation that have distributed our species and its DNA across the world’s surface; the markets through which we exchange goods and services; the clubs we form, as well as the myriad cults, movements, and crazes we periodically produce with minimal premeditation and leadership. And the fourth is hierarchies, vertical organizations characterized by centralized and top-down command, control, and communication. These begin with family-based clans and tribes, out of which or against which more complex hierarchical institutions evolved. They include, too, tightly regulated urban polities reliant on commerce or bigger, mostly monarchical, states based on agriculture; the centrally run cults often referred to as churches; the armies and bureaucracies within states; the autonomous corporations that, from the early modern period, sought to exploit economies of scope and scale by internalizing certain market transactions; academic corporations like universities; political parties; and the supersized transnational states that used to be called empires.

Note that the environment is not wholly a given; it can be shaped by, as well as shape, humanity. It may well be that, in the foreseeable future, our species’ impact on the earth’s climate will become the dominant driver of history, but that is not yet the case. For now, the interactions of networks and hierarchies are more important. Networks are not planned by a single authority; they are the main source of innovation but are relatively fragile. Hierarchies exist primarily because of economies of scale and scope, beginning with the imperative of self-defense. To that end, but for other reasons too, hierarchies seek to exploit the positive externalities of networks. States need networks, for no political hierarchy, no matter how powerful, can plan all the clever things that networks spontaneously generate. But if the hierarchy comes to control the networks so much as to compromise their benign self-organizing capacities, then innovation is bound to wane.

Consider some examples of history along these four axes. The population of the entire Eurasian landmass was devastated by the Black Death of the 14th century, a natural disaster transmitted along trade networks. But the impact was very different in Europe compared with Asia. The main difference between the West and the East of Eurasia after 1500 was that networks in the West were much freer from hierarchical dominance than in the East. No monolithic empire rose in the West; multiple and often weak principalities prevailed. Printing existed in China long before the 15th century, but its advent in Germany was explosive because of the network effects generated by the rapid spread of Gutenberg’s easily replicated technology. The Reformation, which was printed as much as it was preached, unleashed a wave of religious revolt against the hierarchy of the Roman Catholic Church. It was only after prolonged and bloody conflict that the monarchies were able to re-impose their hierarchical control over the new Protestant sects.

European history in the 17th, 18th, and 19th centuries was characterized by a succession of network-driven waves of innovation: the Scientific Revolution, the Enlightenment, and the Industrial Revolution. In each case, the sharing of novel ideas within networks of scholars and tinkerers produced powerful and mainly positive externalities, culminating in the decisive improvements in economic efficiency and then life expectancy experienced in the British Isles, Western Europe, and North America from the late 18th century. The network effects of trade and migration were especially powerful, as European merchants and settlers exploited falling transportation costs to export their ideas, as well as their techniques and goods, to the rest of the world. Thanks to those ideas, this was also an era of political revolutions. Ideas about liberty, equality, and fraternity crossed the Atlantic as rapidly as pirated technology from the cotton mills of Lancashire. Kings were toppled, aristocracies abolished, and churches dissolved or made to compete without the support of a state.

Yet the 19th century saw the triumph of hierarchies over the new networks. This was partly because hierarchical corporations—which began, let us remember, as state-sponsored monopolies like the East India Company—were as important in the spread of industrial capitalism as horizontally structured markets. Firms could reduce the transaction costs of the market as well as exploit economies of scale and scope. The railways, steamships, and telegraph cables that made possible the first age of globalization had owners.

The key, however, was the victory of hierarchy in the realm of politics. Why revolutionary ideologies like Jacobinism and Marxism-Leninism so quickly produced highly centralized hierarchical political structures is one of the central puzzles of the modern era, though it was an outcome more or less accurately predicted by much classical political theory. Whatever the democratic aspirations of the revolutionaries, their ideologies ended up as sources of legitimation for autocrats who were markedly more power-hungry than the monarchs of the ancien régime.

True, the energies unleashed by the overthrow of the Bourbons were (just barely) insufficient to overcome those produced by the British synthesis of monarchism and the pursuit of Mammon, which restored or revived the continental monarchies, including, temporarily, the Bourbons themselves. But the old order was only partially restored. Napoleon had taught even his most ardent enemies an unforgettable lesson, as Clausewitz understood, about how an imperial leader could wield power by commanding a people in arms.

For a time it seemed that a modus vivendi had arisen between the new networks of science and industry and the old hierarchies of hereditary rule. Half the world fell under the sway of a dozen Western empires, and much of the rest was under their economic sway. But optimists, from Norman Angell to Andrew Carnegie, felt sure that these empires would not be so foolish as to jeopardize the benefits of international exchange. After all, it was partly by taxing the fruits of the first era of globalization that the empires could finance their vast armies, navies, and bureaucracies. This proved wrong. So complete was the imperial system of command, control, and communication that when the empires resolved to go to war with one another over arcane issues like the status of Bosnia-Herzegovina or the neutrality of Belgium, they were able to mobilize in excess of seventy million men as soldiers or sailors. In France and Germany about a fifth of the prewar population ended up in uniform, bearing arms.
 
Part 2

The triumph of hierarchy over networks was symbolized by the complete failure of the Second International of socialist parties to prevent the World War. When the leaders of European socialism met in Brussels at the end of July 1914, they could do little more than admit their own impotence. What the Viennese satirist Karl Kraus called the alliance of “thrones and telephones” had marched the young men of Europe off to Armageddon. Those who thought the war would not last long underestimated the hierarchical state’s ability to sustain industrialized slaughter.

The mid 20th century was the zenith of hierarchy. Although World War I ended with the collapse of no fewer than four of the great dynastic empires—the Romanov, Habsburg, Hohenzollern, and Ottoman—they were replaced with astonishing swiftness by new and stronger states based on the normative paradigm of the nation-state, the ethno-linguistically defined anti-imperium.

Not only did the period after 1918 witness the rise of the most centrally controlled states of all time (Stalin’s Soviet Union, Hitler’s Third Reich and Mao’s People’s Republic); it was also an era in which hierarchies flourished in the economic, social and cultural spheres. Central planners ruled, whether they worked for governments, armies or large corporations. In Aldous Huxley’s Brave New World (1932), the Fordist World State controls everything from eugenics to narcotics and euthanasia; the fate of the non-conformist Bernard Marx is banishment. In Orwell’s Nineteen Eighty-Four (1949) there is not the slightest chance that Winston Smith will be able to challenge Big Brother’s rule over Airstrip One; his fate is to be tortured and brainwashed. A remarkable number of the literary heroes of the high Cold War era were crushed by one system or the other: from Heller’s John Yossarian to le Carré’s Alec Leamas to Solzhenytsin’s Ivan Denisovich.

Kraus was right: The information technology of mid-century overwhelmingly favored the hierarchies. Though the telegraph and telephone created vast new networks, they were relatively easy to cut, tap, or control. Newsprint, radio, cinema, and television were not true network technologies because they generally involved one-way communication from the content provider to the reader or viewer. During the Cold War the superpowers were mostly able to control information flows by manufacturing or sponsoring propaganda and classifying or censoring anything deemed harmful. Sensation surrounded every spy scandal and defection; yet in most cases all that happened was that classified information was passed from one national security state to the other. Only highly trained personnel in governmental, academic, or corporate research centers used computers, and those were anything but personal computers. The self-confidence of the technocrats at that time is nicely exemplified by MONIAC (the Monetary National Income Analogue Computer), a hydraulic device designed by Bill Phillips (of Phillips Curve fame) that was supposed to simulate the effects of Keynesian economic policy on the UK economy.



There were moments of truth, particularly in the 1970s, when classified information reached the public through the free press in the West or through samizdat literature in the Soviet bloc. Yet the striking feature of the later Cold War was how well the national security state managed to withstand exposures like the report of the Church Committee or the publication of the Gulag Archipelago. George H.W. Bush, appointed head of the Central Intelligence Agency in 1976—in the midst of the Church Committee’s work—went on to serve as Vice President and President. Within a decade of the collapse of the Soviet Union, the Russian Federation had a former KGB operative as its President. The Pentagon proved to be mightier than the Pentagon Papers.

Today, by contrast, the hierarchies seem to be in much more trouble. The most obvious challenge to established hierarchies is the flow of information unleashed by the advent of the personal computer, email, and the internet, which have allowed ordinary citizens to organize themselves into much larger and more dispersed networks than has ever been possible before. The PC has empowered the individual the way the book did after the 15th-century breakthrough in printing. Indeed, the trajectories for the production and price of PCs in the United States between 1977 and 2004 are remarkably similar to the trajectories for the production and price of printed books in England from 1490 to 1630. The differences are that our networking revolution is much faster and that it is global.

In a far shorter space of time than it took for 84 percent of the world’s adults to become literate, a remarkably large proportion of humanity has gained access to the internet. Although its origins can be traced back to the late 1960s, the internet as a system of interconnected computer networks did not really begin until the standard protocol suite (TCP/IP) was adopted at universities in the 1980s. As recently as 1998 only around 2 percent of the world’s population were internet users. Today the proportion is 39 percent; in the developed world, 77 percent.

Google was incorporated in 1998. Its first premises were a garage in Menlo Park. Today its has the capacity to process more than a billion search requests and 24 petabytes of user-generated data every day. Facebook was founded at Harvard ten years ago. Today it has 1.23 billion regular users a month. Twitter was created eight years ago. Now it has 200 million users, who send more than 400 million tweets daily.

The challenge these new networks pose to established hierarchies is threefold. First, they vastly increase the volume of information to which citizens can have access, as well as the speed with which they can have access to it. Second, they empower individual citizens to publicize things that might otherwise remain secret or known only to a few. Edward Snowden and Daniel Ellsberg did the same thing by making public classified documents, but Snowden has already revealed much more than Ellsberg and to vastly more people, while Julian Assange, the founder of WikiLeaks, has far out-scooped Carl Bernstein and Bob Woodward (even if he has not yet helped to bring down an American President). Third, and perhaps most importantly, the networks expose by their very performance the inefficiency of hierarchical government.

Politicians and voters remain the captives of a postwar campaign vocabulary in which the former pledge to the latter that they will provide not just additional public goods but also “create jobs” without significantly increasing the cost to most voters in terms of taxation. The history of President Barack Obama’s Administration can be told as a series of pledges to increase employment (“the stimulus”), reduce the risk of financial crisis, and provide universal health insurance. The President’s popularity has declined fastest when, as with the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, the inability of the Federal government to fulfill these pledges efficiently has been most exposed. The shortcomings of the website Healthcare.gov in many ways epitomized the fundamental problem: In the age of Amazon, consumers expect basic functionality from websites. Daily Show host Jon Stewart spoke for hundreds of thousands of frustrated users when he taunted former Health and Human Services head Kathleen Sebelius: “I’m going to try and download every movie ever made, and you’re going to try to sign up for Obamacare, and we’ll see which happens first.”

Yet the trials and tribulations of “Obamacare” are merely a microcosm for a much more profound problem. The modern state, at least in its democratic variant, has evolved a familiar solution to the problem of increasing the provision of public goods without making proportionate increases to taxation, and that is to finance current government consumption through borrowing, while at the same time encouraging citizens to increase their own leverage by various fiscal incentives, such as the deductibility of mortgage interest payments. The vast increase of private debt that preceded the financial crisis of 2008 was succeeded by a comparably vast increase in public debt. At the same time, central banks took increasingly unorthodox steps to shore up tottering banks and plunging asset markets by purchases of securities in exchange for excess reserves. With short-term interest rates at zero, “quantitative easing” was designed to keep long-term interest rates low too. The financial world watches with bated breath to see how QE can be “tapered” and when short-term rates will be raised. Most economists nevertheless take for granted the U.S. government’s ability to print its own currency without limit. Many assume that this offers some relatively easy way out of trouble if rising interest rates threaten to make debt service intolerably burdensome. But this assumption may be wrong.

Since ancient times, states have exploited their ability to issue currency, whether coins stamped with the king’s likeness or electronic dollars on a screen. But if the new networks are in the process of creating an alternative form of money, such as Bitcoin purports to be, then perhaps the time-honored state privilege to debase the currency is at risk. Bitcoin offers many advantages over a fiat currency like the U.S. dollar. As a means of payment—especially for online transactions—it is faster, cheaper, and more secure than a credit card. As a store of value it has many of the key attributes of gold, notably finite supply. As a unit of account it is having teething troubles, but that is because it has become an attractive speculative object. It is too early to predict that Bitcoin will succeed as a parallel currency, but it is also too early to predict that it will fail. In any case, governments can fail, too.

Where governments fail most egregiously, new networks may well increase the probability of successful revolution. The revolutionary events that swept the Middle East and North Africa beginning in Tunisia in December 2010—the so-called Arab Spring—were certainly facilitated by various kinds of information technology, even if for most Arabs it was probably the television channel Al Jazeera more than Facebook or Twitter that spread the news of the revolution. Most recently, the revolutionaries in Kiev who overthrew Ukrainian President Viktor Yanukovych made effective use of social networks to organize their protests in the Maidan and to disseminate their critique of Yanukovych and his cronies.

Yet it would be naive to assume that we are witnessing the dawn of a new era of free and equal netizens, all empowered by technology to speak truth to (and about) power, just as it would be naive to assume that the hierarchical state is doomed, if not to revolutionary downfall then at least to a permanent diminution of its capacity for social control.

Modern networks have prospered, paradoxically, in ways that are profoundly inegalitarian. That is because ownership of the information infrastructure and the rents from it are so concentrated. Google at the time of writing is worth $359 billion by market capitalization. About 16 percent of its shares, worth $58 billion, are owned by its founders, Larry Page and Sergey Brin. The market capitalization of Facebook is $161 billion; 28 percent of the shares, worth $45 billion, are owned by its founder Mark Zuckerberg. If Thomas Piketty needs further proof of his thesis that the world is reverting to the inequality of a century ago because, absent world wars and revolutions, the rate of return on capital (and the rate of growth of executive compensation) tends to outstrip the rate of growth of aggregate income, it is there in abundance in Silicon Valley. Granted, the young and very wealthy people who literally own the modern networks tend to have somewhat liberal political views. A few of them are libertarians. But few of them would welcome Gallic rates of taxation, much less a French-style egalitarian revolution.



At the same time, the hierarchical state has not been slow to appreciate the opportunities that the new social networks present. Edward Snowden’s most startling revelation was the complicity of companies like Google, Apple, Yahoo, and Facebook in the National Security Agency’s global surveillance programs, notably PRISM. It is all very well for Mark Zuckerberg to complain that he has been “so confused and frustrated by the repeated reports of the behavior of the U.S. government” and to declare self-righteously: “When our engineers work tirelessly to improve security, we imagine we’re protecting you against criminals, not our own government.” But he knows full well that since at least 2009 Facebook has responded to tens of thousands of U.S. government requests for information about Facebook users. If not for Snowden’s leaks, we would not have known just how freely the NSA was making use of the provisions of the Foreign Intelligence Surveillance Act.

The owners of the networks are also well aware that plotting jihad is not the principal use to which their technology is put, any more than plotting revolution is. They owe their security much more to network surfers’ apathy than to the NSA. Most people do not go online to participate in flash mobs. Most women seem to prefer shopping and gossiping; most men prefer sports and pornography. All those neural quirks produced by evolution make us complete suckers for the cascading stimuli of tweets, Instagrams, and Facebook pokes from members of our electronic kinship group. The networks cater to our solipsism (selfies), our short attention spans (140 characters), and our seemingly insatiable appetite for “news” about “celebrities.”

In the networked world, the danger is not popular insurrection but indifference; the political challenge is not to withstand popular anger but to transmit any kind of signal through the noise. What can focus us, albeit briefly, on the tiresome business of how we are governed or, at least, by whom? When we speak of “populism” today, we mean simply a politics that is audible as well as intelligible to the man in the street. Not that the man in the street is actually in the street. Far more likely, he is the man slumped on his sofa, his attention skipping fitfully from television to laptop to tablet to smartphone and back to television. And what gets his attention? The end of history? The clash of civilizations? The answer turns out to be the narcissism of small differences.

Liberals denounce conservatives with astonishing vituperation; Republicans inveigh against Democrats. But to the rest of the world what is striking are the strange things nearly all Americans agree about (for example, that children should be packed off to camps in the summer). Many English people are outraged about immigrant Romanians. But to East Asian eyes the English are scarcely distinguishable from Romanians. (Indeed, in many parts of formerly working-class England people live much as the reviled Roma are alleged to: in squalor.)

It is no accident that most of the world’s conflicts today are not between civilizations, as Samuel Huntington foresaw, but between neighbors. That, after all, is what is really going on in Syria, Iraq, and the Central African Republic, not to mention Ukraine. Can anyone other than a Russian or a Ukrainian tell a Russian and a Ukrainian apart? And yet how readily one is pitted against the other, and how distractingly.

At times, it can seem as if we are condemned to try to understand our own time with conceptual frameworks more than half a century old. Since the financial crisis that began in 2007, many economists have been reduced to recycling the ideas of John Maynard Keynes, who died in 1946. At the same time, analysts of international relations seem to be stuck with terminology that dates from roughly the same period: “realism” or “idealism”, containment or appeasement. (George Kennan’s “Long Telegram” was dispatched just two months before Keynes’s death.)

Yet our own time is profoundly different from the mid-20th century. The near-autarkic, commanding and controlling states that emerged from the Depression, World War II, and the early Cold War exist only as pale shadows of their former selves. Today, the combination of technological innovation and international economic integration has created entirely new forms of organization—vast, privately owned networks—that were scarcely dreamt of by Keynes and Kennan. We must ask ourselves: Are these new networks really emancipating us from the tyranny of the hierarchical empire-states? Or will the hierarchies ultimately take over the networks as they did a century ago, in 1914, successfully subordinating them to the priorities of the national security state?

A libertarian utopia of free and equal netizens—all networked together, sharing all available data with maximum transparency and minimal privacy settings—has a certain appeal, especially to the young. It is romantic to picture these netizens, like the workers in Lang’s Metropolis, spontaneously rising up against the world’s corrupt hierarchies. Yet the suspicion cannot be dismissed that, despite all the hype of the Information Age and all the brouhaha about Messrs. Snowden and Assange, the old hierarchies and new networks are in the process of reaching a quiet accommodation with one another, much as thrones and telephones did a century ago. We shall all know what it means when (as begins to be imaginable) Sheryl Sandberg leans all the way into the White House. It will mean that Metropolis lives on.

Niall Ferguson is Laurence A. Tisch Professor of History at Harvard and senior fellow at the Hoover Institution. His most recent book is The Great Degeneration: How Institutions Decay and Economies Die (Penguin Press).
 
A few riffs on the Libertarian theme. I'm not too sure that Libertarian populism is the term I would use, but there are many different ways to skin the cat:

Breaking the Banks and Government with Libertarian Populism:
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=l0v15DmtLw0&feature=youtu.be

Glenn Reynolds interviews Conn Carol

and more on how Libertarianism as a Social Movement is evolving with changes in technology:

http://washingtonexaminer.com/large-government-out-of-place-in-a-society-based-on-small-technology/article/2553178

Large government out of place in a society based on small technology
BY MICHAEL BARONE | SEPTEMBER 11, 2014 | 5:00 AM
TOPICS: BARACK OBAMA LABOR HISTORY TECHNOLOGY GOVERNMENT REGULATION SMARTPHONES

Photo - Civilian technology has gone "small" -- nanotechnology, genetic engineering, custom-engineered materials, "mass customization" through 3-D printing. If the Rouge plant looming over Dearborn was the iconic symbol of the industrial age, the iconic symbol of our information age is the smartphone in your pocket. (Compassionate Eye Foundation/Justin Pumfrey/Getty)

Civilian technology has gone "small" -- nanotechnology, genetic engineering, custom-engineered...
“Twentieth-century technology,” writes economic historian Joel Mokyr in the Manhattan Institute’s excellent City Journal, “was primarily about ‘large’ things.”

Large in physical size, that is. Mokyr’s examples include the diesel engine and the gas turbine, shipping containers, communications satellites launched by giant rockets, oil-drilling platforms, massive power stations, giant steel mills and huge airplanes.

Most are familiar sights today, but if we try to see them with the eyes of someone in 1914, they are awe-inspiring. This summer, I drove past the ruins of Henry Ford’s Highland Park plant, the largest manufacturing plant in the world when it opened in 1910. There, Ford set up the first auto assembly line and in 1914, the same year Europe went to war, started paying his workers $5 a day.

Three years later, the year the United States entered what was called the Great War, Ford started building the even larger Rouge plant in Dearborn, covering 960 acres — one-and-a-half square miles — with 100 miles of internal railroad track. More than 100,000 men worked there daily at its peak. A drive around the perimeter of the Rouge plant puts five miles on your odometer.

To the men and women of 1914, these plants, like the giant steel factories along Cleveland’s Cuyahoga River and Pittsburgh’s Monongahela, must have been breathtaking. Most people then grew up on farms where the highest structure around was a church steeple.

Breathtaking too was the audacity of the entrepreneurs and capitalists who raised the money and designed these behemoths and many others.

Consider what immigrants, many on ocean liners among the largest ever built, saw as they entered New York Harbor in 1914. Giant ships sailing past the Statue of Liberty toward the skyscrapers of lower Manhattan, the offices of John D. Rockefeller at 26 Broadway and J.P. Morgan at 23 Wall Street, and behind them the gleaming new the 60-story Gothic Woolworth Building, the tallest building in the world when it was completed in 1913 and until the Chrysler Building rose in 1930.

“Large” technology tended to encourage large bureaucracies and large government. You needed bureaucratic organization and centralized control to manage those 100,000 workers at the Rouge and, eventually, big unions as well. In 1913 and 1914 Congress created the Federal Reserve and the Federal Trade Commission and passed the Clayton Antitrust Act. It seemed natural when so much wealth was so visibly accumulated that government and labor unions should have some countervailing power.

Large technology also meant large armies — and enormous casualties in war. Some 116,000 Americans died in World War I, far more than the less than 10,000 in Iraq and Afghanistan combined. Other nations’ (approximate) death tolls were much higher: 800,000 British, 1.3 million French, 1.8 million Germans, 1.3 million Austro-Hungarians, and 2 million Russians. On July 1, 1916, the first day of the Battle of the Somme, 19,000 British soldiers died and 41,000 were wounded.

These figures are orders of magnitude larger than the death tolls in recent wars. And so are the sizes of militaries. Military historian Robert Scales recently noted how General George Patton’s mechanized war doctrine, waged with enormous forces, culminated in the march to Baghdad in 2003. Enemies adapted, however, and Patton’s mass armies have been replaced by special operations forces, pioneered by General Stanley McChrystal — “small units of superbly selected, educated, led and bonded soldiers.”

Civilian technology, Joel Mokyr notes, has also gone “small” — nanotechnology, genetic engineering, custom-engineered materials, “mass customization” through 3-D printing. If the Rouge plant looming over Dearborn was the iconic symbol of the industrial age, the iconic symbol of our information age is the smartphone in your pocket.

“Large” technology requires the standardization of masses of people, centralized command-and-control, conformity to social norms. Massive work forces and massive armies cannot operate optimally otherwise.

“Small” technology enables individuals to make personal choices, fashion their world to their own dimensions, deploy their own talents and pursue their interests in ways of their own choosing. Standardization yields to customization.

President Obama doesn’t seem to get this. He sees history as a story of progress from minimal government to ever-larger government. He’s only sorry that he hasn’t taken us farther on that track.

But history doesn’t proceed in a straight line; it moves around. “Large” technology made big government seem necessary in 1914. “Small” technology requires something different, something more adaptive today.
 
Status
Not open for further replies.
Back
Top